I will again summarize an article from Zerkalo Nedeli, again written by Elena Borodina, but this time not
dealing with small-scale producers, but the largest producers in Ukraine. The
article with the title “Unequal Marriage without Government Oversight” was
published on August 21 and can be found here
(in Russian). The point of the article is to question the degree to which the
super large agroholdings will really contribute to national and/or rural
development, which is sometimes claimed by advocates of agroholdings (including
even the World Bank).
Borodina first gives an account of the polarization of the
agrarian sector towards either really small or really large farms, where many
people in rural areas are becoming landless while land is being concentrated
more and more under agroholdings. At the beginning of 2014, she states, the number
of agroholdings approached 140, which controlled 6000 separate farming
enterprises (40% of the total), on about 8 million ha of land (40% of the land
cultivated by farming enterprises). Of all registered farming operations, these
agroholdings harvest about 50% of Ukrainian winter wheat, more than half of the
corn and rapeseed, a third of the sunflower seeds, and over 80% of chicken
meat. Because land reform has not been completed (among other things,
agricultural land sales are as yet not allowed in Ukraine), a “shadow” land
market has arisen, which these companies benefit from, and it helps them
attract capital.
So these companies do attract capital, which they invest in
operations, but, as Borodina points out, there appears to be an inverse
relationship between the growth of investment in the agrarian sector and the
number of people employed in the agrarian sector. Below I have reproduced a
graph using the same data as in her diagram in ZN (note: the original graph
measured investment in Ukrainian Hryvnia, but I changed that into dollars using
the average annual exchange rate for that year. Export sales and many inputs
are often dominated in USD so this makes sense, especially considering the
devaluation of the UAH in 2008).
Borodina also points out that the agroholdings are very good
at attracting capital either through IPOs and stock emissions or thanks to their
access to inexpensive credit from international financial institutions such as
the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) and the
International Finance Corporation (IFC) which is part of the World Bank, and
export credit agencies of different countries like Austria and Denmark. For
example, the Danish Export Credit Agency, from 2003 to 2011, insured the export
of livestock products valued at 154 million Euro, from Ukraine. The International
Finance Corporation has since 2010 provided financing in support of Ukrainian agribusiness
to the tune of 282 million dollars, while the EBRD, over the last 5 years, has
presented credits totaling 55 million Euro to some of the largest agroholdings
in Ukraine.
The larger point that Borodina seeks to make is that all
this support to large-scale agribusiness in Ukraine will not lead to the
development of the countryside, but is rather a factor contributing to the
ongoing distortion and polarization of the agrarian sector in Ukraine.